{smcl} {* 17dec2020}{...} {cmd:help ceqcoverage} (beta version; please report bugs) {right:Sean Higgins} {hline} {title:Title} {p 4 11 2} {hi:ceqcoverage} {hline 2} Computes indicators on coverage and leakages for fiscal interventions (taxes, transfers, and subsidies) by income group for the "E18. Coverage Tables" sheets of the CEQ Master Workbook 2016 Section E {pstd} {ul:Caution:} The construction of the CEQ income concepts Market Income, Market Income plus Pensions, Net Market Income, Gross Income, and Taxable Income will differ depending on which scenario for the public contributory pension system has been chosen. In the public contributory Pensions as Deferred Income (PDI) scenario, pension system income is treated as (Market) income earned previously deferred until today; while pension system contributions are treated as mandatory savings (income deferred to one’s future self). In contrast, the contributory Pensions as Government Transfer(PGT) scenario, pension system income is treated as a pure transfer (from the fisc), while pension system contributions are treated as a tax. In the PDI scenario pensions are prefiscal income while in the PGT scenario the public contributory pension system is a fiscal tax and transfer system that redistributes income from today’s working-age population to today’s pension-age population. When the user wishes to analyze both PDI and PGT scenarios, this command must be run twice: once for outputting information generated under the PDI scenario to a Masterworkbook (section E); and again for outputting information generated under the PGT scenario to its own Masterworkbook (section E). See also the Income concepts options section below for more detail. {title:Syntax} {p 8 11 2} {cmd:ceqcoverage} {ifin} {weight} [{cmd:using} {it:filename}] [{cmd:,} {it:options}]{break} {synoptset 29 tabbed}{...} {synopthdr} {synoptline} {syntab:Income concepts} {synopt :{opth m:arket(varname)}}Market income{p_end} {synopt :{opth mp:luspensions(varname)}}Market income plus pensions{p_end} {synopt :{opth n:etmarket(varname)}}Net market income{p_end} {synopt :{opth g:ross(varname)}}Gross income{p_end} {synopt :{opth t:axable(varname)}}Taxable income{p_end} {synopt :{opth d:isposable(varname)}}Disposable income{p_end} {synopt :{opth c:onsumable(varname)}}Consumable income{p_end} {synopt :{opth f:inal(varname)}}Final income{p_end} {syntab:Fiscal Interventions} {synopt :{opth p:ensions(varlist)}}Contributory pension variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth dtr:ansfers(varlist)}}Direct transfer variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth dtax:es(varlist)}}Direct tax variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth cont:ribs(varlist)}}Contribution variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth su:bsidies(varlist)}}Subsidy variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth indtax:es(varlist)}}Indirect tax variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth health(varlist)}}Health variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth educ:ation(varlist)}}Education variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth other:public(varlist)}}Other public in-kind transfers{p_end} {synopt :{opth userfeesh:ealth(varlist)}}Health user fees variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth userfeese:duc(varlist)}}Education user fees variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth userfeeso:ther(varlist)}}Other public user fees variables{p_end} {syntab:Direct Beneficiary Markers} {synopt :{opth recp:ensions(varlist)}}Contributory pension variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth recdtr:ansfers(varlist)}}Direct transfer variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth paydtax:es(varlist)}}Direct tax variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth payco:ntribs(varlist)}}Contribution variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth recsu:bsidies(varlist)}}Subsidy variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth payindtax:es(varlist)}}Indirect tax variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth rechealth(varlist)}}Health variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth receduc:ation(varlist)}}Education variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth recother:public(varlist)}}Other public in-kind transfers{p_end} {synopt :{opth payuserfeesh:ealth(varlist)}}Health user fees variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth payuserfeese:duc(varlist)}}Education user fees variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth payuserfeeso:ther(varlist)}}Other public user fees variables{p_end} {syntab:PPP conversion} {synopt :{opth ppp(real)}}PPP conversion factor (LCU per international $, consumption-based) from year of PPP (e.g., 2005 or 2011) to year of PPP; do not use PPP factor for year of household survey{p_end} {synopt :{opth cpib:ase(real)}}CPI of base year (i.e., year of PPP, usually 2005 or 2011){p_end} {synopt :{opth cpis:urvey(real)}}CPI of year of household survey{p_end} {synopt :{opt da:ily}}Indicates that variables are in daily currency{p_end} {synopt :{opt mo:nthly}}Indicates that variables are in monthly currency{p_end} {synopt :{opt year:ly}}Indicates that variables are in yearly currency (the default){p_end} {pstd} Note that the default PPP conversion factors and default income cutoffs are related. See Income group cut-offs options for a more detailed explanation. {syntab:Survey information} {synopt :{opth hs:ize(varname)}}Number of members in the household (should be used when each observation in the data set is a household){p_end} {synopt :{opth hh:id(varname)}}Unique household identifier variable (should be used when each observation in the data set is an individual){p_end} {synopt :{opth psu(varname)}}Primary sampling unit; can also be set using {help svyset:svyset}{p_end} {synopt :{opth s:trata(varname)}}Strata (used with complex sampling desings); can also be set using {help svyet:svyset}{p_end} {syntab:Income group cut-offs} {synopt :{opth cut1(real)}}Upper bound (exclusive) income for ultra-poor; default is $1.90 PPP per day{p_end} {synopt :{opth cut2(real)}}Upper bound (exclusive) income for extreme poor; default is $3.20 PPP per day{p_end} {synopt :{opth cut3(real)}}Upper bound (exclusive) income for moderate poor; default is $5.50 PPP per day{p_end} {synopt :{opth cut4(real)}}Upper bound (exclusive) income for vulnerable; default is $11.50 PPP per day{p_end} {synopt :{opth cut5(real)}}Upper bound (exclusive) income for middle class; default is $57.60 PPP per day{p_end} {syntab:Ignore missing values} {synopt :{opt ignorem:issing}}Ignore any missing values of income concepts and fiscal interventions {syntab:Export directly to CEQ Master Workbook (requires Stata 13 or newer)} {synopt :{opth coun:try(string)}}Country{p_end} {synopt :{opth surv:eyyear(string)}}Year of survey{p_end} {synopt :{opth auth:ors(string)}}Authors of study{p_end} {synopt :{opth base:year(real)}}Base year of PPP conversion (e.g., 2005, 2011){p_end} {synopt :{opth scen:ario(string)}}Scenario{p_end} {synopt :{opth grou:p(string)}}Group{p_end} {synopt :{opth proj:ect(string)}}Project{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheetm(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by market income. Default is "E18.m Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheetmp(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by market income plus pensions. Default is "E18.m+p Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheetn(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by net market income. Default is "E18.n Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheetg(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by gross income. Default is "E18.g Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheett(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by taxable income. Default is "E18.t Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheetd(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by disposable income. Default is "E18.d Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheetc(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by consumable income. Default is "E18.c Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheetf(string)}}Name of sheet to write results ranking by final income. Default is "E18.f Coverage Tables"{p_end} {synopt :{opt open}}Automatically open CEQ Master Workbook with new results added{p_end} {synoptline} {p 4 6 2} {cmd:pweight} allowed; see {help weights}. Alternatively, weights can be specified using {help svyset}. {title:Description} {pstd} {cmd:ceqcoverage} calculates coverage and leakage indicators by income group for fiscal interventions (taxes, transfers, and subsidies), where income groups are defined holding the income concept fixed within each sheet. Hence, {cmd:ceqcoverage} produces one sheet for each of the CEQ core income concepts; the income concept defining the ranking of each sheet will be referred to in this help file as the ranking variable. The coverage and leakage indicators include total benefits by group, the distribution of benefits (what percent of benefits goes to each group), the number of direct beneficiaries (i.e., the person who directly receives the transfer or directly pays the tax), the number of beneficiary households, the number of direct and indirect beneficiaries (i.e., members of beneficiary households), the distribution of beneficiary households and direct and indirect beneficiaries (what percent of beneficiaries belong to each group), coverage within each group (what percent of households or people in that group receive benefits), and mean benefits (per beneficiary household and per beneficiary). {pstd} The fiscal interventions are specified using fiscal intervention options. Note that each option takes a {varlist} that can (and often should) have greater than one variable: the variables provided should be as disaggregated as possible. For example, there might be survey questions about ten different direct cash transfer programs; each of these would be a variable, and all ten variables would be included with the {opth dtr:ansfers(varlist)} option. Contributory pensions are specified by {opth p:ensions(varlist)}, direct transfers by {opth dtr:ansfers(varlist)}, direct taxes (not including contributions) by {opth dtax:es(varlist)}}, contributions (including variables for both employer and employee contributions if applicable) by {opth co:ntribs(varlist)}, indirect subsidies by {opth su:bsidies(varlist)}, indirect taxes by {opth indtax:es(varlist)}, health benefits by {opth health(varlist)}, education benefits by {opth educ:ation(varlist)}, and other public in-kind benefits by {opth other:public(varlist)}, health user fees by {opth userfeesh:ealth(varlist)}, education user fees by {opth userfeese:duc(varlist)}, and other public user fees by {opth userfeeso:ther(varlist)}. Tax and contribution variables may be saved as either positive or negative values, as long as one is used consistently for all tax and contribution variables. The same goes for user fees variables. The variables provided in the {opth health(varlist)}, {opth educ:ation(varlist)}, and {opth other:public(varlist)} options should already be net of co-payments and user fees; we nevertheless include the separate options {opth userfeesh:ealth(varlist)}, {opth userfeese:duc(varlist)}, and {opth userfeeso:ther(varlist)} so that, for example, user fees can be analyzed. {pstd} Note that to estimate the number of direct beneficiaries (i.e., the person who directly receives the transfer or directly pays the tax), an additional piece of information is needed: which individuals in the household directly received a particular transfer or directly paid a particular tax. This information cannot be obtained from the fiscal interventions variables described above, since those variables are already at the household per capita level, i.e., they would be positive for all direct *and indirect* beneficiaries (other members of the direct beneficiary's household). Thus, this command includes the "direct beneficiary marker" options where, for each fiscal intervention variable given in the fiscal intervention options, a variable identifying which individuals are direct beneficiaries (or payers) of that fiscal intervention is given. These options are {opth recp:ensions(varlist)} for direct beneficiaries of contributory pensions (where the "rec" prefix on the option is short for "recipient"); {opth recdtr:ansfers(varlist)} for direct beneficiaries of direct transfers; {opth paydtax:es(varlist)} for direct payers of direct taxes; {opth payco:ntribs(varlist)} for direct payers of contributions; {opth recsu:bsidies(varlist)} for direct beneficiaries of subsidies; {opth payindtax:es(varlist)} for direct payers of indirect taxes; {opth receduc:ation(varlist)} for direct beneficiaries of education benefits; {opth rechealth(varlist)} for direct beneficiaries of health benefits; {opth recother:public(varlist)} for direct beneficiaries of other public benefits; {opth payuserfeese:duc(varlist)} for direct payers of education user fees; {opth payuserfeesh:ealth(varlist)} for direct payers of health user fees; and {opth payuserfeeso:ther(varlist)} for direct payers of other user fees. {pstd} For a data set at the individual level, the variables supplied to the direct beneficiary marker options should be dummy variables that equal 1 if the individual is a direct beneficiary/payer and 0 otherwise. For a data set at the household level, they should equal the number of household members that are direct beneficiaries/payers. For each category of fiscal intervention, the number of variables supplied to these options must be the same as the number of variables supplied to the corresponding fiscal intervention variables, and they should be supplied in the same order. For example, suppose the data set is at the individual level, there are two levels of education: primary and secondary, and that household per capita benefits are included in {cmd:pc_primary} and {cmd:pc_secondary}, and dummy variables identifying which individuals are the direct beneficiaries are {cmd:db_primary} and {cmd:db_secondary}. Then the fiscal intervention and direct beneficiary marker options for education would be {cmd:educ(pc_primary pc_secondary) receduc(db_primary db_secondary)}. For fiscal interventions for which the survey does not specify who is the direct beneficiary (e.g., if a question only asks whether anyone in the household receives benefits from a program), mark one member of the household (e.g. the head) as a direct beneficiary. {pstd} {cmd: ceqcoverage} automatically converts local currency variables to PPP dollars, using the PPP conversion factor given by {opth ppp(real)}, the consumer price index (CPI) of the year of PPP (e.g., 2005 or 2011) given by {opth cpib:ase(real)}, and the CPI of the year of the household survey used in the analysis given by {opth cpis:urvey(real)}. The year of PPP, also called base year, refers to the year of the International Comparison Program (ICP) that is being used, e.g. 2005 or 2011. The survey year refers to the year of the household survey used in the analysis. If the year of PPP is 2005, the PPP conversion factor should be the "2005 PPP conversion factor, private consumption (LCU per international $)" indicator from the World Bank's World Development Indicators (WDI). If the year of PPP is 2011, use the "PPP conversion factor, private consumption (LCU per international $)" indicator from WDI. The PPP conversion factor should convert from year of PPP to year of PPP. In other words, when extracting the PPP conversion factor, it is possible to select any year; DO NOT select the year of the survey, but rather the year that the ICP was conducted to compute PPP conversion factors (e.g., 2005 or 2011). The base year (i.e., year of PPP) CPI, which can also be obtained from WDI, should match the base year chosen for the PPP conversion factor. The survey year CPI should match the year of the household survey. Finally, for the PPP conversion, the user can specify whether the original variables are in local currency units per day ({opt da:ily}), per month ({opt mo:nthly}), or per year ({opt year:ly}, the default assumption). {pstd} If the data set is at the individual level (each observation is an individual), the variable with the identification code of each household (i.e., it takes the same value for all members within a household) should be specified in the {opth hh:id(varname)} option; the {opth hs:ize(varname)} option should not be specified. If the data set is at the household level, the number of members in the household should be specified in {opth hs:ize(varname)}; the {opth hh:id(varname)} option should not be specified. In either case, the weight used should be the household sampling weight and should {it:not} be multiplied by the number of members in the household since the program will do this multiplication automatically in the case of household-level data. {pstd} There are two options for including information about weights and survey sample design for accurate estimates and statistical inference. The sampling weight can be entered using {weight} or {help svyset}. Information about complex stratified sample designs can also be entered using {help svyset} since {cmd:ceqcoverage} automatically uses the information specified using {help svyset}. Alternatively, the primary sampling unit can be entered using the {opth psu(varname)} option and strata can be entered using the {opth s:trata(varname)} option. {pstd} By default, {cmd: ceqcoverage} does not allow income concept or fiscal intervention variables to have missing values: if a household has 0 income for an income concept, receives 0 from a transfer or a subsidy, or pays 0 of a tax, the household should have 0 rather than a missing value. If one of these variables has missing values, the command will produce an error. For flexibility, however, the command includes an {opt ignorem:issing} option that will drop observations with missing values for any of these variables, thus allowing the command to run even if there are missing values. {marker opt} {title:Options} {marker cor} {dlgtab:Core options} {phang} {opt using} is required, and indicates the filename for the output. Results are automatically exported to the CEQ Master Workbook if {cmd:using} {it:filename} is specifed in the command, where {it:filename} is the Master Workbook. By default, {cmd:ceqcoverage} prints to the sheets titled "E18.X Coverage Tables" where X indicates the income concept (m, m+p, n, g, t, d, c, f); the user can override the sheet names using the {opt sheetm(string)}, {opt sheetmp(string)}, {opt sheetn(string)}, {opt sheetg(string)}, {opt sheett(string)}, {opt sheetd(string)}, {opt sheetc(string)}, and {opt sheetf(string)} options, respectively. Exporting directly to the Master Workbook requires Stata 13 or newer. The Master Workbook populated with results from {cmd:ceqcoverage} can be automatically opened if the {opt open} option is specified (in this case, {it:filename} cannot have spaces). Results are also saved in matrices available from {cmd:return list}. {p 8 8 2} Notice that if the user wishes to do the CEQ {it} Assessment {sf} for both the {bf: "pensions as deferred income scenario"} and {bf: "pensions as government transfer scenario"}, the ado does {bf: NOT} run both scenarios automatically. The user must run the ado twice, one time per scenario (see Income concepts options for an explanation on the differences across scenarios), and create two separate sets of E sheets. Hence, {it:filename} should be changed accordingly. {marker inc} {dlgtab:Income concepts options} {pstd} The CEQ core income concepts include market income, market income plus pensions, net market income, gross income, taxable income, disposable income, consumable income, and final income. The variables for these income concepts, which should be expressed in local currency units (preferably {bf:per year} for ease of comparison with totals from national accounts), are indicated using the {opth m:arket(varname)}, {opth mp:luspensions(varname)}, {opth n:etmarket(varname)}, {opth g:ross(varname)}, {opth t:axable(varname)}, {opth d:isposable(varname)}, {opth c:onsumable(varname)}, and {opth f:inal(varname)} options. {pstd} The public contributory old-age pension system can be incorporated into a CEQ Assessment as deferred income or as a government transfer (for a detailed discussion regarding the alternatives see Lustig (2018) available at {browse "http://commitmentoequity.org/publications-ceq-handbook"}). The decision regarding the public contributory pension system can have a significant impact on assessing the redistributive power of a fiscal system, especially in countries with a high proportion of retirees and large spending on social security. The construction of Market income, Market income plus pensions, Gross income, Net market income, and Taxable Income will differ between the PDI and PGT scenarios (while Disposable income, Consumable income and Final income are equivalent in value in both scenarios). The user must create two separate sets of E sheets, one per scenario (for a more detailed explanation see {cmd: using} in {help ceqlorenz##cor:core options}). {pstd} In CEQ {it} Assessments {sf} in the {bf: "pensions as deferred income scenario"}, it is assumed that contributions during working years are a form of “forced saving” and income concepts are defined in the following way: {p 16 16 10} Market income given by {opth m:arket(varname)} as factor income (wages and salaries and income from capital) plus private transfers (remittances, private pensions, etc.) {bf: PLUS} imputed rent and own production {bf: MINUS} contributions to social insurance old-age pensions. {p 16 16 10} Market income plus pensions given by {opth mp:luspensions(varname)} as Market income (PDI) {bf: PLUS} contributory social insurance old-age pensions. Prefiscal income (PDI) is defined as Market income plus Pensions (PDI). {p 16 16 10} Gross Income given by {opth g:ross(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PDI) {bf: PLUS} direct cash and near cash transfers (conditional and unconditional cash transfers, school feeding programs, free food transfers, etc.). {p 16 16 10} Net Market Income given by {opth n:etmarket(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PDI) {bf: MINUS} direct taxes and {bf: MINUS} non-pension social contributions. {p 16 16 10} Taxable income given by {opth t:axable(varname)} as Gross Income (PDI) {bf: MINUS} all non-taxable Gross Income components. {p 16 16 10} Disposable income given by {opth d:isposable(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PDI) {bf: PLUS} all direct transfers {bf: MINUS} all direct taxes and non-pension social contributions. {pstd} In the {bf: "pensions as government transfer scenario"}, it is assumed that pensions are a pure government transfers and income concepts are defined in the following way: {p 16 16 10} Market income given by {opth m:arket(varname)} as factor income (wages and salaries and income from capital) plus private transfers (remittances, private pensions, etc.) {bf: PLUS} imputed rent and own production. Prefiscal income (PGT) is defined as Market income (PGT). {p 16 16 10} Market income plus pensions given by {opth mp:luspensions(varname)} as Market income (PGT) {bf: PLUS} contributory social insurance old-age pensions. {p 16 16 10} Gross Income given by {opth g:ross(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PGT) {bf: PLUS} direct cash and near cash transfers (conditional and unconditional cash transfers, school feeding programs, free food transfers, etc.). {p 16 16 10} Net Market Income given by {opth n:etmarket(varname)} as Market Income (PGT) {bf: MINUS} direct taxes and {bf: MINUS} non-pension social contributions. {p 16 16 10} Taxable income given by {opth t:axable(varname)} as Gross Income (PGT) {bf: MINUS} all non-taxable Gross Income components. {p 16 16 10} Disposable income given by {opth d:isposable(varname)} as Market Income (PGT) {bf: MINUS} all direct taxes {bf: PLUS} pension income {bf: PLUS} all other direct transfers {bf: MINUS} all pension and non-pension social contributions. {pstd} The construction of Consumable and Final income is done in the same way in both the PDI and PGT scenarios: {p 16 16 10} Consumable income given by {opth c:onsumable(varname)} as Disposable Income {bf: PLUS} indirect subsidies (energy, food and other general or targeted price subsidies) and {bf: MINUS} indirect taxes (VAT, excise taxes, and other indirect taxes). {p 16 16 10} Final income given by {opth f:inal(varname)} as Consumable income {bf: PLUS} Monetized value of in-kind transfers in education and health services at average government cost and {bf: MINUS} co-payments and user fees. {marker cut} {dlgtab:Income group cut-offs options} {pstd} {opth cut1(real)} to {opth cut5(real)} are in $PPP. The default cut-off values of $1.90, $3.20 and $5.50 correspond to the income-category-specific poverty lines suggested in Joliffe & Prydz (2016), who determined the median (to the nearest 10 cents) national poverty line in $PPP (using the 2011 ICP PPP conversion factors) for each set of countries grouped under the World Bank's income classification system. Specifically, there are three income class-specific poverty lines: US$1.90 a day for low income countries, US$3.20 a day for lower middle- income countries and US$5.50 a day for upper middle-income countries. Thus, in the context of middle-income countries, we call those living on less than US$1.90 PPP per day the “ultra-poor.” The US$3.20 and US$5.50 PPP per day poverty lines are commonly used as extreme and moderate poverty lines for Latin America and roughly correspond to the median official extreme and moderate poverty lines in those countries. {pstd} The $11.50 and $57.60 cutoffs correspond to cutoffs for the vulnerable and middle-class populations suggested for the 2005-era PPP conversion factors by Lopez-Calva and Ortiz-Juarez (2014); $11.50 and $57.60 represent a United States CPI-inflation adjustment of the 2005-era $10 and $50 cutoffs. The US$10 PPP per day line is the upper bound of those vulnerable to falling into poverty (and thus the lower bound of the middle class) in three Latin American countries, calculated by Lopez-Calva and Ortiz-Juarez (2014). Ferreira and others (2013) find that an income of around US$10 PPP also represents the income at which individuals in various Latin American countries tend to self-identify as belonging to the middle class and consider this a further justification for using it as the lower bound of the middle class. The US$10 PPP per day line was also used as the lower bound of the middle class in Latin America in Birdsall (2010) and in developing countries in all regions of the world in Kharas (2010). The US$50 PPP per day line is the upper bound of the middle class proposed by Ferreira and others (2013). {pstd} The user may specify any set of cut points that create exclusive population groups. For example, the older cut points for the ultra-poor, extreme poor, moderate poor, vulnerable and middle class, which corresponded to the 2005-era PPP conversion factors were $1.25, $2.50, $4, $10 and $50 (respectively). {title:Examples} {pstd}Locals for PPP conversion (obtained from WDI through the {cmd: wbopendata} command){p_end} {phang} {cmd:. local ppp = 1.5713184 // 2005 Brazilian reais per 2005 $ PPP}{p_end} {phang} {cmd:. local cpi = 95.203354 // CPI for Brazil for 2009}{p_end} {phang} {cmd:. local cpi05 = 79.560051 // CPI for Brazil for 2005}{p_end} {pstd}Individual-level data (each observation is an individual){p_end} {phang} {cmd:. ceqcoverage [pw=w] using C:/MWB2016_E18.xlsx, hhid(hh_code) psu(psu_var) strata(stra_var) m(ym) mplusp(ymplusp) n(yn) g(yg) t(yt) d(yd) c(yc) f(yf) pens(pensions) dtax(income_tax property_tax) cont(employee_contrib employer_contrib) dtransfer(cct noncontrip_pens unemployment scholarships food_transfers) indtax(vat excise) subsidies(energy_subs) health(basic_health preventative_health inpatient_health) education(daycare preschool primary secondary tertiary) userfeeshealth(user_feesh) userfeeseduc(user_feesed) recpens(db_pensions) paydtax(db_income_tax db_property_tax) paycont(db_employee_contrib db_employer_contrib) recdtransfer(db_cct db_noncontrip_pens db_unemployment db_scholarships db_food_transfers) payindtax(db_vat db_excise) recsubsidies(db_energy_subs) rechealth(db_basic_health db_preventative_health db_inpatient_health) receduc(db_daycare db_preschool db_primary db_secondary db_tertiary) payuserfeesh(db_user_feesh) payuserfeese(db_user_feesed) ppp(`ppp') cpibase(`cpi05') cpisurvey(`cpi') open}{p_end} {title:Saved results} Pending {title:Author} {p 4 4 2}Sean Higgins, CEQ Institute, sean.higgins@ceqinstitute.org {title:References} {pstd}Commitment to Equity (CEQ) {browse "http://www.commitmentoequity.org":website}.{p_end} {phang} Higgins, Sean and Nora Lustig. 2016. {browse "http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304387816300220":"Can a Poverty-Reducing and Progressive Tax and Transfer System Hurt the Poor?"} {it:Journal of Development Economics} 122, 63-75.{p_end} {pstd}Lustig, Nora, editor. 2018. {browse "https://commitmentoequity.org/publications-ceq-handbook":Commitment to Equity Handbook. Estimating the Impact of Fiscal Policy on Inequality and Poverty}. Brookings Institution Press and CEQ Institute, Tulane University. {p_end} {phang} Osorio, R. 2007. "{bf:quantiles}: Stata module to categorize by quantiles." Boston College Department of Economics Statistical Software Components S456856.{p_end}