{smcl} {* 17dec2020}{...} {cmd:help ceqgraph conc} (beta version; please report bugs) {right:Sean Higgins} {hline} {title:Title} {p 4 11 2} {hi:ceqgraph conc} {hline 2} Graphs concentration curves of fiscal interventions, ranked by each core income concept. {pstd} {ul:Caution:} The construction of the CEQ income concepts Market Income, Market Income plus Pensions, Net Market Income, Gross Income, and Taxable Income will differ depending on which scenario for the public contributory pension system has been chosen. In the public contributory Pensions as Deferred Income (PDI) scenario, pension system income is treated as (Market) income earned previously deferred until today; while pension system contributions are treated as mandatory savings (income deferred to one’s future self). In contrast, the contributory Pensions as Government Transfer(PGT) scenario, pension system income is treated as a pure transfer (from the fisc), while pension system contributions are treated as a tax. In the PDI scenario pensions are prefiscal income while in the PGT scenario the public contributory pension system is a fiscal tax and transfer system that redistributes income from today’s working-age population to today’s pension-age population. When the user wishes to analyze both PDI and PGT scenarios, this command must be run twice: once for outputting information generated under the PDI scenario to a Masterworkbook (section E); and again for outputting information generated under the PGT scenario to its own Masterworkbook (section E). See also the Income concepts options section below for more detail. {title:Syntax} {p 8 11 2} {cmd:ceqgraph} {cmdab:conc} {ifin} {weight} [{cmd:,} {it:options}]{break} {synoptset 29 tabbed}{...} {synopthdr} {synoptline} {syntab:Income concepts} {synopt :{opth m:arket(varname)}}Market income{p_end} {synopt :{opth mp:luspensions(varname)}}Market income plus pensions{p_end} {synopt :{opth n:etmarket(varname)}}Net market income{p_end} {synopt :{opth g:ross(varname)}}Gross income{p_end} {synopt :{opth t:axable(varname)}}Taxable income{p_end} {synopt :{opth d:isposable(varname)}}Disposable income{p_end} {synopt :{opth c:onsumable(varname)}}Consumable income{p_end} {synopt :{opth f:inal(varname)}}Final income{p_end} {syntab:Fiscal Interventions} {synopt :{opth p:ensions(varlist)}}Contributory pension variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth dtr:ansfers(varlist)}}Direct transfer variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth dtax:es(varlist)}}Direct tax variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth cont:ribs(varlist)}}Contribution variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth su:bsidies(varlist)}}Subsidy variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth indtax:es(varlist)}}Indirect tax variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth health(varlist)}}Health variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth educ:ation(varlist)}}Education variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth other:public(varlist)}}Other public in-kind transfers{p_end} {synopt :{opth userfeesh:ealth(varlist)}}Health user fees variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth userfeese:duc(varlist)}}Education user fees variables{p_end} {synopt :{opth userfeeso:ther(varlist)}}Other public user fees variables{p_end} {syntab:Survey information} {synopt :{opth hs:ize(varname)}}Number of members in the household (should be used when each observation in the data set is a household){p_end} {synopt :{opth hh:id(varname)}}Unique household identifier variable (should be used when each observation in the data set is an individual){p_end} {synopt :{opth psu(varname)}}Primary sampling unit; can also be set using {help svyset:svyset}{p_end} {synopt :{opth s:trata(varname)}}Strata (used with complex sampling desings); can also be set using {help svyet:svyset}{p_end} {syntab:Ignore missing values} {synopt :{opt ignorem:issing}}Ignore any missing values of income concepts and fiscal interventions {syntab:Graphing options} {synopt :{opth scheme(string)}}Set the graph scheme ({stata help scheme}; default is "s1mono"){p_end} {synopt :{opth path(string)}}The directory to save the graphs in{p_end} {synopt :{opth graphname(string)}}The prefix of the saved graph names (default is "conc"){p_end} {synopt :{it:{help twoway_options}}}Any options documented in {bind:{bf:[G] {it:twoway_options}}}{p_end} {syntab:Export directly to CEQ Master Workbook (requires Stata 14.1 or newer)} {synopt :{opth coun:try(string)}}Country{p_end} {synopt :{opth surv:eyyear(string)}}Year of survey{p_end} {synopt :{opth auth:ors(string)}}Authors of study{p_end} {synopt :{opth scen:ario(string)}}Scenario{p_end} {synopt :{opth grou:p(string)}}Group{p_end} {synopt :{opth proj:ect(string)}}Project{p_end} {synopt :{opth sheet(string)}}Name of sheet to write results. Default is "E25. Concentration Curves"{p_end} {synopt :{opt open}}Automatically open CEQ Master Workbook with new results added{p_end} {synoptline} {p 4 6 2} {cmd:pweight} allowed; see {help weights}. Alternatively, weights can be specified using {help svyset}. {title:Description} {pstd} {cmd:ceqgraph conc} graphs concentration curves of fiscal interventions, ranked by each core income concept. For legibility, separate graphs are produced for various categories of fiscal intervention, and a separate set of these graphs is produced for the income ranking corresponding to each of the core income concepts. {pstd} The fiscal interventions are specified using fiscal intervention options. Note that each option takes a {varlist} that can (and often should) have greater than one variable: the variables provided should be as disaggregated as possible. For example, there might be survey questions about ten different direct cash transfer programs; each of these would be a variable, and all ten variables would be included with the {opth dtr:ansfers(varlist)} option. Contributory pensions are specified by {opth p:ensions(varlist)}, direct transfers by {opth dtr:ansfers(varlist)}, direct taxes (not including contributions) by {opth dtax:es(varlist)}}, contributions (including variables for both employer and employee contributions if applicable) by {opth co:ntribs(varlist)}, indirect subsidies by {opth su:bsidies(varlist)}, indirect taxes by {opth indtax:es(varlist)}, health benefits by {opth health(varlist)}, educaiton benefits by {opth educ:ation(varlist)}, and other public in-kind benefits by {opth other:public(varlist)}, health user fees by {opth userfeesh:ealth(varlist)}, education user fees by {opth userfeese:duc(varlist)}, and other public user fees by {opth userfeeso:ther(varlist)}. Tax, contribution and user fees variables may be saved as either positive or negative values, as long as one is used consistently for all tax, contribution and user fees variables. The {opth health(varlist)}, {opth educ:ation(varlist)} and {opth other:public(varlist)} options need to be specfied with fiscal intervention variable(s) that are net of user fee(s). If any of these variables is negative for any households due to user fees exceeding gross benefits, the negative values should be truncated at 0. The user fee options are designed solely to separately analyze the distribution of usre fees and will not be used in calculating net health/education/other public transfers. See the example section for more detail. The variables provided in the {opth health(varlist)}, {opth educ:ation(varlist)}, and {opth other:public(varlist)} options should already be net of co-payments and user fees; we nevertheless include the separate options {opth userfeesh:ealth(varlist)}, {opth userfeese:duc(varlist)}, and {opth userfeeso:ther(varlist)} so that, for example, user fees can be analyzed. {pstd} The income and fiscal intervention variables should be expressed in household per capita or per adult equivalent terms, regardless of whether the data set being used is at the household or individual level. Hence, they should have the same per-person amount for each member within a household when using individual-level data. {pstd} A separate set of graphs is produced for the income ranking corresponding to each of the CEQ core income concepts, which include market income, market income plus pensions, net market income, gross income, taxable income, disposable income, consumable income, and final income. The variables for these income concepts are indicated using the {opth m:arket(varname)}, {opth mp:luspensions(varname)}, {opth n:etmarket(varname)}, {opth g:ross(varname)}, {opth t:axable(varname)}, {opth d:isposable(varname)}, {opth c:onsumable(varname)}, {opth c:onsumable(varname)}, and {opth f:inal(varname)} options. {pstd} If the data set is at the individual level (each observation is an individual), the variable with the identification code of each household (i.e., it takes the same value for all members within a household) should be specified in the {opth hh:id(varname)} option; the {opth hs:ize(varname)} option should not be specified. If the data set is at the household level, the number of members in the household should be specified in {opth hs:ize(varname)}; the {opth hh:id(varname)} option should not be specified. In either case, the weight used should be the household sampling weight and should {it:not} be multiplied by the number of members in the household since the program will do this multiplication automatically in the case of household-level data. {pstd} There are two options for including information about weights and survey sample design for accurate estimates and statistical inference. The sampling weight can be entered using {weight} or {help svyset}. Information about complex stratified sample designs can also be entered using {help svyset} since {cmd:ceqgraph} automatically uses the information specified using {help svyset}. Alternatively, the primary sampling unit can be entered using the {opth psu(varname)} option and strata can be entered using the {opth s:trata(varname)} option. {pstd} By default, {cmd: ceqgraph conc} does not allow income concept or fiscal intervention variables to have missing values: if a household has 0 income for an income concept, receives 0 from a transfer or a subsidy, or pays 0 of a tax, the household should have 0 rather than a missing value. If one of these variables has missing values, the command will produce an error. For flexibility, however, the command includes an {opt ignorem:issing} option that will drop observations with missing values for any of these variables, thus allowing the command to run even if there are missing values. {pstd} Negative incomes are allowed, but a warning is issued for each core income concept that has negative values (or positive values when a fiscal intervention is stored as negative values). This is because various measures are no longer well-behaved when negative values are included (for example, the Gini coefficient, concentration coefficient, or squared poverty gap can exceed 1, and other desirable properties of these measures when incomes are non-negative no longer hold when negative values are allowed). {pstd} The resulting graphs from {cmd:ceqgraph conc} are saved as {bf:`graphname'_`category'_`y'.gph} where `graphname' is the prefix specified by {opth graphname(string)} (or "conc" by default), `y' is a letter representing the income concept used to rank (m, p, n, g, t, d, c, or f), and `category' is a category of fiscal interventions (direct_transfers, direct_taxes, indirect_subsidies, indirect_taxes, inkind, or summary). The final category, summary, summarizes the curves for each of the above broad categories in a single graph. {marker opt} {title:Options} {marker cor} {dlgtab:Core options} {phang} {opt using} is required, and indicates the filename for the output. Results are automatically exported to the CEQ Master Workbook if {cmd:using} {it:filename} is specifed in the command, where {it:filename} is the Master Workbook. By default, {cmd:ceqgraph conc} prints to the sheets titled "E25. Concentration Curves"; the user can override the sheet names using the {opt sheet(string)}. Exporting directly to the Master Workbook requires Stata 14.1 or newer. The Master Workbook populated with results from {cmd:ceqgraph conc} can be automatically opened if the {opt open} option is specified (in this case, {it:filename} cannot have spaces). Results are also saved in matrices available from {cmd:return list}. {p 8 8 2} Notice that if the user wishes to do the CEQ {it} Assessment {sf} for both the {bf: "pensions as deferred income scenario"} and {bf: "pensions as government transfer scenario"}, the ado does {bf: NOT} run both scenarios automatically. The user must run the ado twice, one time per scenario (see Income concepts options for an explanation on the differences across scenarios), and create two separate sets of E sheets. Hence, {it:filename} should be changed accordingly. {marker inc} {dlgtab:Income concepts options} {pstd} The CEQ core income concepts include market income, market income plus pensions, net market income, gross income, taxable income, disposable income, consumable income, and final income. The variables for these income concepts, which should be expressed in local currency units (preferably {bf:per year} for ease of comparison with totals from national accounts), are indicated using the {opth m:arket(varname)}, {opth mp:luspensions(varname)}, {opth n:etmarket(varname)}, {opth g:ross(varname)}, {opth t:axable(varname)}, {opth d:isposable(varname)}, {opth c:onsumable(varname)}, and {opth f:inal(varname)} options. {pstd} The public contributory old-age pension system can be incorporated into a CEQ Assessment as deferred income or as a government transfer (for a detailed discussion regarding the alternatives see Lustig (2018) available at {browse "http://commitmentoequity.org/publications-ceq-handbook"}). The decision regarding the public contributory pension system can have a significant impact on assessing the redistributive power of a fiscal system, especially in countries with a high proportion of retirees and large spending on social security. The construction of Market income, Market income plus pensions, Gross income, Net market income, and Taxable Income will differ between the PDI and PGT scenarios (while Disposable income, Consumable income and Final income are equivalent in value in both scenarios). The user must create two separate sets of E sheets, one per scenario (for a more detailed explanation see {cmd: using} in {help ceqlorenz##cor:core options}). {pstd} In CEQ {it} Assessments {sf} in the {bf: "pensions as deferred income scenario"}, it is assumed that contributions during working years are a form of “forced saving” and income concepts are defined in the following way: {p 16 16 10} Market income given by {opth m:arket(varname)} as factor income (wages and salaries and income from capital) plus private transfers (remittances, private pensions, etc.) {bf: PLUS} imputed rent and own production {bf: MINUS} contributions to social insurance old-age pensions. {p 16 16 10} Market income plus pensions given by {opth mp:luspensions(varname)} as Market income (PDI) {bf: PLUS} contributory social insurance old-age pensions. Prefiscal income (PDI) is defined as Market income plus Pensions (PDI). {p 16 16 10} Gross Income given by {opth g:ross(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PDI) {bf: PLUS} direct cash and near cash transfers (conditional and unconditional cash transfers, school feeding programs, free food transfers, etc.). {p 16 16 10} Net Market Income given by {opth n:etmarket(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PDI) {bf: MINUS} direct taxes and {bf: MINUS} non-pension social contributions. {p 16 16 10} Taxable income given by {opth t:axable(varname)} as Gross Income (PDI) {bf: MINUS} all non-taxable Gross Income components. {p 16 16 10} Disposable income given by {opth d:isposable(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PDI) {bf: PLUS} all direct transfers {bf: MINUS} all direct taxes and non-pension social contributions. {pstd} In the {bf: "pensions as government transfer scenario"}, it is assumed that pensions are a pure government transfers and income concepts are defined in the following way: {p 16 16 10} Market income given by {opth m:arket(varname)} as factor income (wages and salaries and income from capital) plus private transfers (remittances, private pensions, etc.) {bf: PLUS} imputed rent and own production. Prefiscal income (PGT) is defined as Market income (PGT). {p 16 16 10} Market income plus pensions given by {opth mp:luspensions(varname)} as Market income (PGT) {bf: PLUS} contributory social insurance old-age pensions. {p 16 16 10} Gross Income given by {opth g:ross(varname)} as Market Income plus pensions (PGT) {bf: PLUS} direct cash and near cash transfers (conditional and unconditional cash transfers, school feeding programs, free food transfers, etc.). {p 16 16 10} Net Market Income given by {opth n:etmarket(varname)} as Market Income (PGT) {bf: MINUS} direct taxes and {bf: MINUS} non-pension social contributions. {p 16 16 10} Taxable income given by {opth t:axable(varname)} as Gross Income (PGT) {bf: MINUS}all non-taxable Gross Income components. {p 16 16 10} Disposable income given by {opth d:isposable(varname)} as Market Income (PGT) {bf: MINUS} all direct taxes {bf: PLUS} pension income {bf: PLUS} all other direct transfers {bf: MINUS} all pension and non-pension social contributions. {pstd} The construction of Consumable and Final income is done in the same way in both the PDI and PGT scenarios: {p 16 16 10} Consumable income given by {opth c:onsumable(varname)} as Disposable Income {bf: PLUS} indirect subsidies (energy, food and other general or targeted price subsidies) and {bf: MINUS} indirect taxes (VAT, excise taxes, and other indirect taxes). {p 16 16 10} Final income given by {opth f:inal(varname)} as Consumable income {bf: PLUS} Monetized value of in-kind transfers in education and health services at average government cost and {bf: MINUS} co-payments and user fees. {title:Examples} {pstd}Individual-level data (each observation is an individual){p_end} {phang} {cmd:. ceqgraph conc [pw=w] using C:/Output_Tables.xlsx, hhid(hh_code) psu(psu_var) strata(stra_var) m(ym) mplusp(ymplusp) ///}{p_end} {phang} {cmd:. c(yc) f(yf) pens(pensions) dtax(income_tax property_tax)}{p_end} {pstd}Household-level data (each observation is a household){p_end} {phang} {cmd:. ceqgraph conc [pw=w] using C:/Output_Tables.xlsx, hsize(members) psu(psu_var) strata(stra_var) m(ym) mp(ymplusp) ///}{p_end} {phang} {cmd:. c(yc) f(yf) pens(pensions) dtax(income_tax property_tax)}{p_end} {title:Saved results} Pending {title:Author} {p 4 4 2}Sean Higgins, CEQ Institute, sean.higgins@ceqinstitute.org {title:References} {pstd}Commitment to Equity (CEQ) {browse "http://www.commitmentoequity.org":website}.{p_end} {pstd}Lustig, Nora, editor. 2018. {browse "https://commitmentoequity.org/publications-ceq-handbook":Commitment to Equity Handbook. Estimating the Impact of Fiscal Policy on Inequality and Poverty}. Brookings Institution Press and CEQ Institute, Tulane University. {p_end}